https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1916/carimarx/4.htm#v23pp64h-048
A Caricature of Marxism and Imperialist Economism
Norway âachievedâ the supposedly unachievable right to self-determination in 1905, in the era of the most rampant imperialism. It is therefore not only absurd, but ludicrous, from the theoretical standpoint, to speak of âunachievabilityâ.
Kievsky wants to refute that by angrily calling us ârationalistsâ. (What has that to do with it? The rationalist con fines himself to purely abstract disquisitions, while we have pointed to a very concrete fact! But perhaps Kievsky is using the foreign word ârationalistâ in the same... how to put it more mildly?... in the same âunhappyâ manner he used the word âextractiveâ at the beginning of his article, when he presented his arguments âin extractive formâ?)
Kievsky reproaches us. For us, he says, âthe important thing is the appearance of phenomena rather than the real substanceâ. Well, let us examine the real substance.
His refutation begins with this example: enactment of a law against trusts does not prove that their prohibition is unachievable. True enough. But the example is an unhappy one, for it militates against Kievsky. Laws are political measures, politics. No political measure can prohibit economic phenomena. Whatever political form Poland adopts, whether she be part of Tsarist Russia or Germany, or an autonomous region, or a politically independent state, there is no prohibiting or repealing her dependence on the finance capital of the imperialist powers, or preventing that capital from buying up the shares of her industries.
The independence Norway âachievedâ in 1905 was only political. It could not affect its economic dependence, nor was this the intention. That is exactly the point made in our theses. We indicated that self-determination concerns only politics, and it would therefore be wrong even to raise the question of its economic unachievability. But here is Kievsky ârefutingâ this by citing an example of political bans being powerless against the economy! What a ârefutationâ!
To proceed. âOne or even many instances of small-scale industry prevailing over large-scale industry is not sufficient to refute Marxâs correct proposition that the general development of capitalism is attended by the concentration and centralisation of production.â
Again, the argument is based on an unfortunate example, chosen to divert the attention (of the reader and the author) from the substance of the issue.
We maintain that it would be wrong to speak of the economic unachievability of self-determination in the same sense as we speak of the unachievability of labour money under capitalism. Not a single âexampleâ of such achievability can be cited. Kievsky tacitly admits we are correct on this point when he shifts to another interpretation of âunachievabilityâ.
Why does he not do so directly? Why does he not openly and precisely formulate his proposition: âself-determination, while achievable in the sense that it is economically possible under capitalism, contradicts development and is therefore either reactionary or merely an exceptionâ?
He does not do so because a clear formulation of this counter-proposition would immediately expose its author, and he therefore tries to conceal it.
The law of economic concentration, of the victory of large-scale production over small, is recognised in our own and the Erfurt programmes. Kievsky conceals the fact that nowhere is the law of political or state concentration recognised. If it were the same kind of lawâif there were such a lawâthen why should not Kievsky formulate it and suggest that it be added to our programme? Is it right for him to leave us with a bad, incomplete programme, considering that he has discovered this new law of state concentration, which is of practical significance since it would rid our programme of erroneous conclusions?
Kievsky does not formulate that law, does not suggest that it be added to our programme, because he has the hazy feeling that if he did he would be making himself a laughing stock. Everyone would laugh at this amusing imperialist Economism if it were expressed openly and if, parallel with the law that small-scale production is ousted by large-scale production, there were presented another âlawâ (connected with the first or existing side by side with it) of small states being ousted by big ones!
To explain this we shall put only one question to Kievsky: Why is it that economists (without quotation marks) do not speak of the âdisintegrationâ of the modern trusts or big banks? Or of the possibility and achievability of such disintegration? Why is it that even the âimperialist Economistâ (in quotation marks) is obliged to admit that the disintegration of big states is both possible and achievable, and not only in general, but, for example, the secession of âsmall nationalitiesâ (please note!) from Russia (§e, Chapter II of Kievskyâs article)?
Lastly, to show even more clearly the lengths to which our author goes, and to warn him, let us note the following: We all accept the law of large-scale production ousting small-scale production, but no one is afraid to describe a specific âinstanceâ of âsmall-scale industry prevailing over large-scale industryâ as a reactionary phenomenon. No opponent of self-determination has yet ventured to describe as reactionary Norwayâs secession from Sweden, though we raised the question in our literature as early as 1914.[1]
Large-scale production is unachievable if, for instance, hand-worked machines remain. The idea of a mechanical factory âdisintegratingâ into handicrafts production is utterly absurd. The imperialist tendency towards big empires is fully achievable, and in practice is often achieved, in the form of an imperialist alliance of sovereign and independentâpolitically independentâstates. Such an alliance is possible and is encountered not only in the form of an economic merger of the finance capital of two countries, but also in the form of military âco-operationâ in an imperialist war. National struggle, national insurrection, national secession are fully âachievableâ and are met with in practice under imperialism. They are even more pronounced, for imperialism does not halt the development of capitalism and the growth of democratic tendencies among the mass of the population. On the contrary, it accentuates the antagonism between their democratic aspirations and the anti-democratic tendency of the trusts.
It is only from the point of view of imperialist Economism, i.e., caricaturised Marxism, that one can ignore, for instance, this specific aspect of imperialist policy: on the one hand, the present imperialist war offers examples of how the force of financial ties and economic interests draws a small, politically independent state into the struggle of the Great Powers (Britain and Portugal). On the other hand, the violation of democracy with regard to small nations, much weaker (both economically and politically) than their imperialist âpatronsâ, leads either to revolt (Ireland) or to defection of whole regiments to the enemy (the Czechs). In this situation it is not only âachievableâ, from the point of view of finance capital, but sometimes even profitable for the trusts, for their imperialist policy, for their imperialist war, to allow individual small nations as much democratic freedom as they can, right down to political independence, so as not to risk damaging their âownâ military operations. To overlook the peculiarity of political and strategic relationships and to repeat indiscriminately a word learned by rote, âimperialismâ, is anything but Marxism.
On Norway, Kievsky tells us, firstly, that she âhad always been an independent stateâ. That is not true and can only be explained by the authorâs burschikose carelessness and his disregard of political issues. Norway was not an independent state prior to 1905, though she enjoyed a very large measure of autonomy. Sweden recognised Norwayâs political independence only after her secession. If Norway âhad always been an independent stateâ, then the Swedish Government would not have informed the other powers, on October 26, 1905, that it recognised Norwayâs independence.
Secondly, Kievsky cites a number of statements to prove that Norway looked to the West, and Sweden to the East, that in one country mainly British, and in the other German, finance capital was âat workâ, etc. From this he draws the triumphant conclusion: âThis example [Norway] neatly fits into our pattern.â
There you have a sample of the logic of imperialist Economism! Our theses point out that finance capital can dominate in âanyâ, âeven independent countryâ, and all the arguments about self-determination being âunachievableâ from the point of view of finance capital are therefore sheer confusion. We are given data confirming our proposition about the part foreign finance capital played in Norway before and after her secession. And these data are supposed to refute our proposition!
Dilating on finance capital in order to disregard political issuesâis that the way to discuss politics?
No. Political issues do not disappear because of Economismâs faulty logic. British finance capital was âat workâ in Norway before and after secession. German finance capital was âat workâ in Poland prior to her secession from Russia and will continue to âworkâ there no matter what political status Poland enjoys. That is so elementary that it is embarrassing to have to repeat it. But what can one do if the ABC is forgotten?
Does this dispense with the political question of Norwayâs status? With her having been part of Sweden? With the attitude of the workers when the secession issue arose?
Kievsky evades these questions because they hit hard at the Economists. But these questions were posed, and are posed, by life itself. Life itself posed the question: Could a Swedish worker who did not recognise Norwayâs right to secession remain a member of the Social-Democratic Party? He could not.
The Swedish aristocrats wanted a war against Norway, and so did the clericals. That fact does not disappear because Kievsky has âforgottenâ to read about it in the history of the Norwegian people. The Swedish worker could, while remaining a Social-Democrat, urge the Norwegians to vote against secession (the Norwegian referendum on secession, held on August 13, 1905, resulted in 368,200 votes for secession and 184 against, with about 80 per cent of the elector ate taking part). But the Swedish worker who, like the Swedish aristocracy and bourgeoisie, would deny the Norwegians the right to decide this question themselves, without the Swedes and irrespective of their will, would have been a social-chauvinist and a miscreant the Social-Democratic Party could not tolerate in its ranks.
That is how §9 of our Party Programme should be applied. But our imperialist Economist tries to lump over this clause. You cannot jump over it, gentlemen, without falling into the embrace of chauvinism!
And what of the Norwegian worker? Was it his duty, from the internationalist point of view, to vote for secession? Certainly not. He could have voted against secession and remained a Social-Democrat. He would have been betraying his duty as a member of the Social-Democratic Party only if he had proffered a helping hand to a Black-Hundred Swedish worker opposed to Norwayâs freedom of secession.
Some people refuse to see this elementary difference in the position of the Norwegian and Swedish worker. But they expose themselves when they evade this most concrete of political questions, which we squarely put to them. They remain silent, try to wriggle out and in that way surrender their position.
To prove that the âNorwegianâ issue can arise in Russia, we deliberately advanced this proposition: in circumstances of a purely military and strategic nature a separate Polish state is fully achievable even now. Kievsky wants to âdiscussâ thatâand remains silent!
Let us add this: Finland too, out of purely military and strategic considerations, and given a certain outcome of the present imperialist war (for instance, Sweden joining the Germans and the latterâs semi-victory), can become a separate state without undermining the âachievabilityâ of even a single operation of finance capital, without making âunachievableâ the buying up of Finnish railway and industrial shares.[2]
Kievsky seeks salvation from unpleasant political issues in an amazing phrase which is amazingly characteristic of all his âargumentsâ: âAt any moment... [that is literally what he says at the end of §c, Chapter I] the Sword of Damocles can strike and put an end to the existence of an âindependentâ workshopâ (a âhintâ at little Sweden and Norway).
That, presumably, is genuine Marxism: a separate Norwegian state, whose secession from Sweden the Swedish Government described as a ârevolutionary measureâ, has been in existence only some ten years. Is there any point in examining the political issues that follow from this if we have read Hilferdingâs Finance Capital and âunderstoodâ it in the sense that âat any momentââif we are to exaggerate then letâs go the whole hog!âa small state might vanish? Is there any point in drawing attention to the fact that we have perverted Marxism into Economism, and that we have turned our pol icy into a rehash of the speeches of case-hardened Russian chauvinists?
What a mistake the Russian workers must have made in 1905 in seeking a republic: finance capital had already been mobilised against it in France, England, etc., and âat any momentâ the âSword of Damoclesâ could have struck it down, if it had ever come into being!
*
*
âThe demand for national self-determination is not ...utopian in the minimum programme: it does not contradict social development, inasmuch as its achievement would not halt that development.â That passage from Martov is challenged by Kievsky in the section in Which he cites the âstatementsâ about Norway. They prove, again and again, the generally known fact that Norwayâs âself-determinationâ and secession did not halt either the development of finance capital generally, or expansion of its operation in particular, or the buying up of Norway by the English!
There have been Bolsheviks among us, Alexinsky in 1908â10, for instance, who argued with Martov precisely at a time when Martov was right! God save us from such âalliesâ!
Notes
[1] [PLACEHOLDER FOOTNOTE.] âLenin
[2] Given one outcome of the present war, the formation of new states in Europe (Polish, Finnish, etc.) is fully âachievableâ without in any way disturbing the conditions for the development of imperialism and its power. On the contrary, this would increase the influence, contacts and pressure of finance capital. But given another outcome, the formation of new states in Hungary, Czechia, etc., is likewise âachievableâ. The British imperialists are already planning this second outcome in anticipation of their victory. The imperialist era does not destroy either the striving for national political independence or its âachievabilityâ within the bounds of world imperialist relationships. Outside these bounds, however, a republican Russia, or in general any major democratic transformations anywhere else in the world are âunachievableâ without a series of revolutions and are unstable without socialism. Kievsky has wholly and completely failed to understand the relation of imperialism to democracy. âLenin
In this text, Lenin criticizes what he calls "Imperialist Economism." According to Lenin, Imperialist Economism is a distorted version of Marxism that focuses solely on economic issues and disregards the political aspects of imperialism. Lenin argues that Imperialist Economism fails to recognize the political struggles and aspirations of oppressed nations under imperialism and reduces all phenomena to economic factors. He criticizes the tendency to downplay the significance of political independence and self-determination for smaller nations, arguing that their achievement is not contradictory to the development of capitalism. Lenin contends that Imperialist Economism overlooks the complex relationship between imperialism and democracy, failing to understand that imperialism can both suppress and foster democratic aspirations depending on the circumstances.